This article will be published in the Spring 2022 issue of The Independent Review.
The term polemic is derived from the Greek noun polemos, meaning war, and the Greek adjective polemikos, meaning warlike or hostile. A polemic is conventionally viewed as contentious, disputative, or combative rhetoric, the intent of which is to espouse or support a particular position and, in so doing, undermine another, via bold, categorical, often overstated claims. Some of the most famous works in Western literature are polemical: Luthers Ninety-five Theses, Swifts Modest Proposal, and Marx and Engelss Communist Manifesto come to mind in this regard, although it should be noted that some would consider Swifts work rather more a burlesque or satire than a polemic per se.
I do not wish to diminish these works by linking them too closely to The 1619 Project, created by Nikole Hannah-Jones and underwritten by the New York Times, but, in formal terms, the project, considered in toto, is clearly a polemic (New York Times Magazine 2019). The intent of this polemic, on one level, is to dislodge the standard chronology and narrative scaffolding of U.S. history by elevating the importance of racial slavery and what some call racial capitalism in explaining both Americas past and our predicament today. On another level, somewhat shrouded, the project aspires to make the case, if not clinch the deal, for reparations to African Americans, reparations due them not only because of slavery, but also because of Jim Crow and decades of state-sponsored discrimination afterward. Indeed, in many ways, The 1619 Project can be seen as an anguished, over-the-top extension of and elaboration on Ta-Nehisi Coatess essay The Case for Reparations, which appeared in The Atlantic in 2014 (Coates 2014).
Lest I be considered ungenerous, let me compliment the New York Times on the graphic design of the August 18, 2019, issue of its Sunday Magazine, and for including the usual puzzles and posers in the back. The rollout of the project was also impressive, particularly in its magnitude. Regarding the content: As the great historian of slavery Eugene Genovese might have put it, it is così così (so-so) at best. The pictures and illustrations work well, and the poetry and literary essays are often moving. Some of the essays devoted to historical themes ably summarize and synthesize specialist literature for general audiences. Others are curiosat times interesting but minora few are deeply flawed, and one is a train wreck.
To cut to the chase, the principal problems with the most objectionable historical piecesthe introductory essay by Hannah-Jones and the essay by Matthew Desmondare linked inextricably to, indeed, grow inexorably out of, the motivation for and animating spirit behind the project. Bluntly put, despite the projects historical trappings, it is decidedly, even aggressively, presentist in orientation. It is the work largely of journalists and engaged scholars, hoping both to help to operationalize New York Times editor Dean Baquets secret 2019 directive to double down on race with the 2020 election in sight, and, as a derivative dividend, to provide support for the growing movement for reparations, as Hannah-Jones, the majordomo of the project, has made clear (Feinberg 2019; Rockett 2019). To me and to other scholars of a nonactivist bent, the spirit behind the project is as chilling as it is brazen, suggesting nothing so much as the famous Party slogan in Orwells 1984: Who controls the past controls the future: who controls the present controls the past.
The same spirit informs the projects research design. Said design, not surprisingly, focuses almost solely on one variable, race, assuming erroneously that, in so doing, the integument shrouding American history will be burst asunderIm using Marxian phraseology intentionally hereexposing at long last Americas seamy underside. Hence the jettisoning of the year 1776 in favor of 1619a year of little historical moment, but one, it is true, in which a small cargo of African indentured servants or slaves was deposited near Port Comfort in the English colony of Virginia (Coclanis 2019). In the modest words of the New York Times, the focus on race and the epiphanic year 1619 will finally allow us to tell our story truthfully (New York Times Magazine 2019, front cover).
Really? I think not. For in viewing the complex tapestry of America through one lens and one lens only, that of race, or, to be more specific, the racial exploitation of blacks by whites, one misses a loteven about race, slavery, and exploitation. For example, as Philip D. Morgans work has demonstrated, there were many more white slaves in Europe in the first half of the seventeenth century than there were African slaves in Virginia or in English North America as a whole (Morgan 2019, 8991). Morgans findings may not mean much to those involved in The 1619 Project, but they are consonant with the rich work of scholars as different as Orlando Patterson and Thomas Sowell, who have documented the presence of slavery in virtually every society all over the world until relatively recently (Patterson 1982; Sowell 2019, 21923). Then there is the work of historian Kevin Bales, who argues that there are more slaves living in the world today than there were during the heyday of the Atlantic slave trade (Bales 2012). And not to belabor the point, but what about Native American slaves, Native American slaveholders, and African American slaveholders in the United States, the last group numbering more than 3,700 in 1830? Regarding that group, many, to be sure, were slaveholders in name only, masters of freed family members in order to keep those free individuals in the South. But others were enslavers root and branch, including owners of large numbers of slaves, such as the now famous Ellisons of Sumter County, South Carolina, and John C. Stanly of New Bern in Craven County, North Carolina, who in the 1820s owned three plantations and 163 slaves (Johnson and Roark 1984; Schweninger 1990, 10412). Even the slavery portion of the tapestry, then, is more complicated than The 1619 Project would have us believe.
The distorted and reductionistic interpretations both of slavery and of American history more generally are related as well to the projects personnel and deployment thereof. Here, I am not questioning the talent and ability of the team assembled, which on the whole is great, but the manner in which the personnel were employed and the uses to which the knowledge and insights on offer were put, or, in some cases, not put. The roster includes many notable academics, artists, and journalists, and editors at the New York Times contend that other highly respected scholars served as consultants for the project. Points taken, but the most glaring interpretive problems with The 1619 Project grow out of the fact that two of the anchor essaysone laying out the interpretive core of the project and one on the era of slaverywere written by people with suspect domain expertise. In at least one case, sound, accurate advice from one of the historical consultants brought in, Leslie M. Harris of Northwestern University, was rejected or disregarded (Harris 2020). As a result, The 1619 Project, pace Hannah-Joness contention, does not afford us the opportunity for the first time to read about the American story truthfully, but rather in a deformed and distorted way, defined rather more by the moral failing of 1619 than the promise of 1776.
Matthew Desmond and the New History of American Capitalism
Slavery figures prominently in a number of essays and mini-essays in The 1619 Project As previously suggested, several of these essays have come under strong fire, mostly notably, Hannah-Joness framing essay and Matthew Desmonds essay on the economic role and legacy of slavery (Hannah-Jones 2019; Desmond 2019). Thus far, Hannah-Joness piece has drawn the most flak, particularly for her dubious contention that one of the primary reasons the colonists decided to declare their independence from Britain was because they wanted to protect the institution of slavery (Hannah-Jones 2019, 18). Several distinguished senior scholars quickly and effectively pushed back against this position, while others called for less insistent versions of Hannah-Joness claim. Eventually, the New York Times begrudgingly qualified the claim, restating it to read among the various motivations that drove the patriots toward independence was a concern that the British would seek or were already seeking to disrupt in various ways the entrenched system of American slavery (Silverstein 2020). Since then, the Gray Lady has qualified other statements, albeit rather surreptitiously (Stephens 2020; Wood 2020).
Hannah-Joness claim regarding the motivation for revolution, however wrongheaded, was at least plausible. And numerous scholars of various political perspectives would actually agree with another controversial claim in her essay, to wit, that Lincolns positions on racial questions were not particularly enlightened (Magness 2020a, 11324). Desmonds argument, however, is implausible, and few scholars of slavery, other than those deeply invested in the New History of American Capitalism (NHAC) narrative, could possibly find it convincing. This, despite the fact that Desmond is a prolific, highly celebrated and lauded scholar, recipient, seemingly inevitably, of a MacArthur genius grantbestowed, as the foundation puts it, on creative people committed to building a more just, verdant, and peaceful world. He pursues such commitments while firmly ensconced at a prestigious Ivy League school.
At first glance, Desmond, despite the résumé, seems an odd choice for the main essay in The 1619 Project. He is a sociologist rather than a historian, and his principal area of specialization is contemporary urban America. He writes in particular on such themes as poverty, housing, inequality, and social justice (Desmond 2016). Early in his career, he also wrote a well-received ethnographic account of wildland firefighters in Arizona (Desmond 2007).
To be fair, Desmond has in fact written on race and race relations as well, having coauthored two related books with his University of Wisconsin dissertation adviser, the well-known sociologist Mustafa Emirbayer, one an award-winning scholarly study attempting to lay out a new theoretical framework for the concept of race, and the other an undergraduate text on race relations, out in a second edition in 2020. The scholarly study, The Racial Order, is not directly concerned with slavery, and, not surprisingly, contains only a few scattered references to the institution. Both editions of the undergraduate text, Race in America, include a brief sectionmuch the same in eachdevoted mostly to U.S. slavery. The synthetic discussion therein is, for the most part, unobjectionable, commonplace stuff, but one line late in the section is at once illuminating and suggestive: American slavery emerged to meet the needs of colonial exploitation and capitalist expansion (Desmond and Emirbayer 2016, 69). For it is the conjunction of slavery, exploitation, and capitalism that both the NHAC and Desmonds essay in The 1619 Project are all about.
Indeed, because Desmond relies almost exclusively on NHAC personnel and the NHAC playbook in his essay, it behooves us to touch briefly on this influential movement before turning to Desmonds essay itself. I have weighed in elsewhere on both the state of economic history qua field and the NHAC movement and its origins, and so I wont tarry here (Coclanis 2018). Suffice it to say that the field of economic history, which in the 1960s and 1970s ranked among the hottest fields in history, crashed and burned in the 1980s and 1990s, particularly in history departments, but to a lesser extent in economics departments as well. The reasons for the collapse differed in the two disciplines. In economics, an increasing mathematization and formal elegance, a growing concern for explanatory parsimony and analytical rigor, and a soaring interest in contemporary problems and forecasting severely damaged messy, nonaxiomatic, difficult-to-model subfields, such as the history of economic thought and economic historyin the case of the history of economic thought rendering it nearly moribund. In history, the decline of economic history had other causes, ranging from the ascent of cultural history in the 1980s to historians infatuation with postmodernism in the 1980s and 1990s to the changing demographics of the profession. There were deeper reasons as well, however, including historians discomfort with economic theory and formal methodssubjects that have been sine qua nons in economic history ever since the rise of the so-called new economic history in the 1960stheir growing disdain for quantification, and, frankly, their frequent uneasiness with economists themselves (Coclanis and Carlton 2001; Coclanis 2010a).
Surprisingly, though, several developments came together in the aughts to pump new life into economic history. In history departments, interest in postmodern approaches and in cultural history more generally declined in a relative sense at least, creating openings for other fields, including economic history. At the same time, growing anxiety in the United States over matters economicwage stagnation, and increasing income and wealth inequality in particularand, toward the end of the decade, problems relating to the Great Recession, spurred both historians and economists to think more about our economic history, and, more broadly, about capitalism qua system not only in the present but also in the past (Schuessler 2013).
Most economists doing so proceeded with the assumption that the ills already mentionedeven those associated with the Great Recessionwere episodic and in principle correctible within the framework of the capitalist economic system via more realistic theory, better data, and policy reform. The origins of the new interest in economic history in history departments differed dramatically, led as it was for the most part by scholars with very different assumptions about capitalism, taking as priors its pernicious nature, bloody origins, illiberal operations, exploitative trajectory, and incapacity for reform. These scholars, associated early on primarily with Ivy League history departments, such as those at Harvard, Cornell, and Brown, constituted the vanguard, spearheading the development of NHAC. Matthew Desmond, author of a celebrated book titled Evicted, has sought shelter and found himself a home in this movement (Clegg 2015; Hilt 2017; Coclanis 2018; Oakes 2020; Magness 2020b).
As I have already suggested, then, devotees of the NHAC approach capitalism far differentlyand far more disapprovinglythan do most mainstream (neoclassically oriented) economists interested in the past or previous generations of historians doing economic history. Whereas the latter groups legitimately can be criticized for paying insufficient attention at times to the history of capitalism, proceeding, as they often did, as though the system were transhistorical, an outgrowth of what Adam Smith referred to as peoples natural propensity to truck, barter, and trade, and leaving it at that, NHAC scholars purport to do otherwise, by contextualizing it, that is to say, situating capitalism in time, locating it in space, and tying it to specific cultures.
In so doing, they generally view capitalism as an illiberal rather than liberal development, inspired and dominated by Europeans and European Americans, and dependent on power asymmetries, brute force, exploitation, and expropriation from the get-go. In the view of Sven Beckert of Harvard, among the most theoretically sophisticated of NHACers, capitalism emerged in the West simultaneously with, and largely dependent upon, slavery and other forms of unfree labor during the early modern period. Most economic historians have traditionally viewed this period in the West as the age of mercantilism, characterized by considerable state intervention in economic life and the extensive use of political power to facilitate and shape market processes and outcomes. Many Marxist and Marxisant scholars focus on the same characteristics, referring to the period variously as early capitalism, the transition to capitalism, or the era of primitive accumulation. Beckert himself emphasizes the state-sponsored violence, employing the term war capitalism as the covering idea for the entire era between c. 1500 and c. 1800. In his viewand in the view of most other scholars in the NAHC traditionslavery was central to capitalisms rise and early expansion. In fact, slavery was one of the defining characteristics of capitalism, putting the lie to interpretations viewing capitalism as a liberal process in which land, labor, and capital were increasingly being specified and individuated, and constraints on the same eased (Beckert 2014).
Not surprisingly, most conventional economic historians view the rise of capitalism as a positive development. Marxists obviously are more ambivalent, but, following Marx himself, have traditionally accepted the possibility that capitalism could at once be progressive and liberal and lead for a time in some areas to an increased dependence on archaic labor systems, whether in the form of the second serfdom in Eastern Europe or slavery in the Americas. NHACers, however, are far less comfortable than their colleagues on the left with the messy ambiguity that is history, and seem to deny this possibility, preferring more dichotomous, categorical formulations: a system is either liberal or illiberal. And in their view, capitalism is illiberalfrom its onset right down to the present daywith the mechanisms by which illiberalism is made manifest changing with capitalisms evolving needs, but characterized and punctuated by power asymmetries, brute force, exploitation, and expropriation wherever it rules and reigns.
To NHACers, then, capitalism and slavery go hand in glove, with the latter in many ways at once an enabler and a signifier of the former. Hence the natural affinity between principals in The 1619 Project and the NHACers, both of whom tether American history and slavery together. Capitalism may or may not have come to America in the first ships, as Carl Degler famously wrote in 1959, but to NHACers its arrival is difficult to deny after the English privateer the White Lion dropped off twenty or so Africanswhether intended as servants or, more likely, as slavesat Port Comfort, Virginia, in August 1619 (Degler 1959, 1; Beckert and Rockman 2016, 127).
Although scholars working in the NHAC vein can in principle write on many topics and themes, thus far the study of slavery, which is viewed as indispensable to the economic development of the United States in the period between the Revolution and the Civil War, has attracted most of their attention, with aspects of the financial history of the country running a distant second (Beckert and Rockman 2016, 1). One of the striking and strikingly disturbing features of Matthew Desmonds procrustean essay for The 1619 Project is that he combines the two themes.
As mentioned earlier, the New History of American Capitalism emerged, fully grown and fully armed, not out of Zeuss head, but out of the Ivies, Harvard in particular, which provided much of the early institutional support. Among the most well-known members of the constellation are the aforementioned Sven Beckert, author of an important book on the global history of cotton; Edward Baptist of Cornell, author of a high-profile and highly controversial 2014 book on slavery; Seth Rockman of Brown, co-editor with Beckert of the NHACs urtext on slavery, Slaverys Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development; Caitlin Rosenthal, Beckerts former student, now a professor at Berkeley; Walter Johnson, another celebrated scholar at Harvard, who doesnt consider himself officially part of the movement, but travels nearby; and historians such as Josh Rothman, Bonnie Martin, and Calvin Schermerhorn (Johnson 2013; Beckert 2014; Baptist 2014; Rothman 2014; Schermerhorn 2015; Martin 2016; Beckert and Rockman 2016; Rosenthal 2018).
Close critical analysis of the NHAC, let alone the constitutive parts thereof, lies beyond the scope of this essay. Fortunately, both the movement and individual works within it have already engendered considerable critical literature, and I myself have contributed to it (Clegg 2015; Olmstead and Rhode 2015; Hilt 2017; Coclanis 2018; Olmstead and Rhode 2018; Wright 2020; Oakes 2020; Magness 2020a; Magness 2020b). Suffice it to say that the criticism of the NHAC position on slavery is in part factual, in part interpretive, and in part formal. Many challenge the basic historical facts arrayed by NHAC scholars, particularly when the facts in question involve numbers or even rudimentary quantitative manipulation. Economists have been especially critical of NHACers use of numbers, which is understandable in light of the fact that with a few notable exceptionsRosenthal and Louis Hyman, the latter of whom doesnt study slavery, come to mindNHACers are, in a scholarly sense, essentially innumerate.
Other critics zero in on interpretive matters. Exhibit A: The NHAC scholars elevate the importance of slavery in explaining not only early American economic development but also, as in The 1619 Project, the main contours of American history. In some cases, this critical path aligns closely with the path discussed in the previous paragraph. The basic numbers on slavery and on cotton, the Souths most important staple in the nineteenth century, just dont support the interpretive weight NHACers bestow on the same. And Exhibit B: For all their concern about capitalism, few NHAC scholars have attempted to define it, which renders their work squishy and suspect, not to mention makes many of their assertions about capitalism unfalsifiable.
Still other critics focus on the ungracious and ungenerous tendency of NHAC scholars to pronounce that they rediscovered slavery as a topic of inquiry, recovering it from the dustbin of history, as it were; to proceed as though they were among the first to study the relationship between capitalism and slavery, a relationship with which both mainstream and Marxist/Marxisant scholars have been wrestling for generations; and in many cases to decline to engage with, to stonewall, or to even attempt to cancel their critics (Coclanis 2018). These critical foci are not necessarily exclusive, with some scholars reproving NHAC work on more than one of these groundsor other grounds.
After this brief introduction to the NHAC approach and personnel, it is time to consider Desmond, who is not a historian, let alone a historian of slavery, much less a historian of slavery who has spent time in the archives. His work on and understanding of slavery is thus derivative, subject to and dependent largely on scholarly intermediation. His coauthored text on race relations suggests, however, that he has long been comfortable with an NHAC take on North American slavery, and his essay for The 1619 Project at once supports and reflects this proposition. Indeed, he has not merely leaned on NHAC personnel and the NHAC playbook, but, seemingly channeling Sheryl Sandberg, has leaned in with a vengeance. How else can one characterize an author who, invoking NHAC claims, attempts to establish direct links between Southern planters in the antebellum period and the Great Recession, union-busting, gig jobs, and even Martin Shkreli!
To Desmond, the conceptual link between and among all of this is low-road capitalismWisconsin sociologist Joel Rogerss terma contemptible form of capitalism purportedly pioneered by preternatural Southern planters on their antebellum plantations, the first big businesses in America (Wright and Rogers 2015, 21644). When a capitalist society goes low, according to Desmond, wages are depressed as businesses compete over the price, not the quality of goods; so-called unskilled workers are typically incentivized through punishments, not promotions; inequality reigns and poverty spreads (Desmond 2019, 32). For evidence that the Souths so-called enslavers not merely fit, but cast the mold for, low-road capitalism, Desmond relies almost exclusively on NHAC concepts, claims, errors, and misconceptions.
To summarize his position: Enslavers, along with their enablers in banking and finance, created large modern slave-labor camps, aka plantations in the South. These camps were central to the American economy, particularly those whose enslaved workforce grew cotton for export, as cotton constituted the lifeblood of the antebellum American economy. To maximize returns, the enslavers, along with the middle managers in the camps, aka overseers, worked slaves mercilessly and overspecialized in cotton. In so doing, they consistently pushed enslaved workers to labor harder, to pick more cotton, and so on. Utilizing management tools ranging from surveillance to the lash, enslavers tried to squeeze as much as possible out of enslaved workers (Desmond 2019).
Desmond, following the NHAC position again, believes that the enslavers consistently demonstrated their managerial bona fides via closely calibrated coercion and, even more, through the meticulous accounts they kept and accounting methods and tools they employed, including relatively sophisticated accounting concepts, most notably, the concept of depreciation. Enslavers fixation on accounting was of a piece with their involvement in the most advanced precincts of banking and finance at the time. Indeed, processes and procedures developed in the course of financing slave sales and especially the cotton export trade led to innovations that at once anticipated and helped to bring about modern banking and finance. Such innovations clearly helped to enrich enslavers and the Southern economy and ipso facto helped the U.S. economy to grow, but they also rendered the South and the nation susceptible to bouts of overspeculation and financial peculation, leading to routine bank failures and intermittent financial panics and collapses, as of course is also true today. In his essay, Desmond focuses on the Panic of 1837, which in his (and the NHACer) view was nothing if not analogous to our own Great Recession, both caused in large part by low-road financial chicanery, lack of regulation or oversight, and the like (Desmond 2019).
The Problems with Desmonds Essay and NHACs Interpretation of Slavery
Desmonds melodramatic narrative, like that of The 1619 Project generally, is as tendentious as it is thinly sourced. Except for a one-off nod in the direction of the distinguished economic historian of slavery Stanley Engerman, virtually every authority invoked and assertion made in Desmonds piece is associated with the NHAC movement and its take on slavery and capitalism (Engerman 2000, 480). Indeed, although the piece is not footnoted, most of it seems to have been drawn from a single textSlaverys Capitalism, edited by Beckert and Rockmansupplemented by a sideways glance at Johnsons River of Dark Dreams. To be sure, an author has the right to his or her own path, but in a publication intended for a broad, nonspecialist audience, doesnt every author also have an obligation to point out that there are other paths and that the path depicted has its critics and detractors? Had Desmond opted for complete transparency, he might even have pointed out that almost every serious economic historian of slavery has rejectedin most instances to devastating effectthe basic NHAC positions he lays out in his essay.
Numerous critics of the NHAC narrative have written convincing rebuttals to various parts of their narrative. But two highly respected economic historians of agriculture, Alan Olmstead of the University of California, Davis, and Paul Rhode of the University of Michigan, should be singled out for the breadth, analytical rigor, and degree of empirical support behind their dismantlementsome would say eviscerationof the NHAC line on the Cotton South. It would be in fact difficult to overstate how convincingly Olmstead and Rhode made the economic case against NHAC assertions in their widely read 2018 essay in Explorations in Economic History. Aiming their critical fire at the primi inter pares behind (or at least associated with) the movementBeckert, Johnson, and especially BaptistOlmstead and Rhode methodically destroy the principal economic contentions of each (Olmstead and Rhode 2018).
Concerning the NHAC talking points integral to Desmonds The 1619 Project piece, Olmstead and Rhode, backed by other economic historians, counter with a much less extreme and much more balanced picture. The South, relatively speaking, was a wealthy region in the antebellum period, and its economy was both dynamic and growing at the time of the Civil War. Slave plantations were central to the regions economy and important to the U.S. economy as a whole. Large plantations, which constituted a small share of the regions total stock of agricultural units, grew a number of staples for export, the most important of which was cotton. The importance of export staples notwithstanding, most parts of the region were self-sufficient in the production of foodstuffs, and corn, not cotton, was the most valuable crop grown in the region. Although cotton was the leading U.S. export throughout the antebellum period, it was nowhere near as important to the U.S. economy as NHACers, basing their position on Baptist, assert, actually constituting less than 5 percent of GDP over most of the antebellum period, and never more than 7 percent (Hansen 2014; Olmstead and Rhode 2018, 12; Magness 2020a, 714, 3136, 5567; Wright 2020, 37378).
Slave-based agriculture was profitable and viable for most slave owners, but did not necessarily benefit nonslaveholders living in the region or promote the long-term development of the region as a whole. Whether slavery did or did not reflect a low-road form of capitalism, it is clear that slave labor was not cheap, but expensive, much more so than labor in other cotton-producing areas in the nineteenth century, such as India. Slavery was a moral enormity and was based on unconscionable exploitation, but there is little evidence for what Baptist refers to as the pushing system in cotton picking. Although daily picking rates, generally speaking, rose dramatically over the course of the antebellum period, the principal reason was not due to the systematic ratcheting up of labor requirements, much less to the creation of a labor regime whose bottom gear was torture, but to westward movement onto better cotton lands and to a series of mechanical, organizational, and, most important, biological innovations in cotton cultivation that together over time increased the total cotton in each boll and on each plant, the total cotton output, and the output per worker (Olmstead and Rhode 2008; Hansen 2014; Olmstead and Rhode 2018; Magness 2020a; Wright 2020).
However important cotton was to the South and to the United States in the antebellum periodand it was importantit was neither indispensable to American economic development nor served as the model or prototype for American capitalism as it developed after slaverys demise. Indeed, the type of agricultural regime that came to characterize the South in the post-slavery eralow-wage, low-skill, and labor-intensivediffered significantly from both the much more capital-intensive, scientific agricultural system emerging in other parts of the country and, obviously, from the nations growing industrial economy, particularly in the manufacturing belt (Coclanis 2000; Coclanis 2020). One additional reason for the NHAC mischaracterization: Its proponents make the mistake, as Gavin Wright has recently noted, of equating the role, nature, and economic importance of cotton in the United States in the antebellum period with that of sugar in the small islands in the British Caribbean in the eighteenth century, a monumental interpretive error (Wright 2020, 36773).
Much of the preceding discussion relates to the NHAC/Desmond position on slavery and agriculture. In his piece, however, Desmond also adopts and extends the NHAC position on finance and banking, linking slavery not just to American financial and banking innovation in the nineteenth century, but well beyond, even to present-day neoliberal policies, financialization, and, as we have seen, even to infamous incarcerated pharmaceutical executive Martin Shkreli.
With such concerns in mind, a few words on Desmonds over-the-top take on slavery, banking, and finance are in order. As was the case with agriculture, Desmond depends almost solely on NHAC claims in making the absurd links already mentioned. The work of five NHAC scholars in particularBonnie Martin, Edward Baptist, Calvin Schermerhorn, Josh Rothman, and Caitlin Rosenthalis relied upon. Martins work and Baptists work are used to demonstrate the importance of slaves as collateral for mortgages of one type or another in the antebellum South and in international finance; Schermerhorns on the importance of the slave trade in the development of U.S. debt and financial instruments; Rothmans to illustrate the speculatory fever that gripped the South intermittently, never more so than in the mid-1830s in Mississippi; Rosenthals to document planters accounts, or, more to the point, the advanced and sophisticated nature of the same. Let us take up these purported harbingers of financialization one by one.
First, Desmond argues that utilizing slavesa legal class of assets constituting almost half of Southern wealth and 19 percent of U.S. wealth in 1860as collateral for securing debt is somehow prima facie evidence that the financialization of the U.S. economy began neither in the reckless speculation of the 1920s, nor with Bretton Woods, nor even with the gutting of the Glass-Steagall Act late in the twentieth century, but in the antebellum South. To Desmond, the story begins with slavery (Wright 2006, 60; Desmond 2019, 37; Williamson and Cain 2020).
Had Desmond bothered to explore more carefully the history of mortgages (including chattel mortgages), the use of collateral, hypothecation, and so on, over time and across space, he would soon have found that mortgages have been around since classical times and there was nothing new or particularly innovative about the use of the same in the antebellum South. Throughout American history, items of valueparticularly items that retained value, were easy to liquidate, and were fungiblewere used as collateral to secure loans and debts. Among the items employed in the United States in the antebellum period were land (especially when cleared), crops, livestock, trade merchandise, tools and fixed capital, urban real estate, household goods, stock certificates, life-insurance policies, and slaves (Murphy 2005, 61920; Kilbourne 2006; Murphy 2017, 6).
The last category of assets was used with great frequency in the South, as one would expect of an asset constituting so large a portion of regional wealth, but slave collateral did have certain disadvantages from the creditors point of view: the value of slaves fluctuated; slaves did not retain value over time; and their fungibility was not unlimited. At one point in his piece Desmond deigns to admit that [e]nslavers were not the first ones to securitize assets and debts in America, but he nonetheless tries to tether slaveholders to collateralized debt obligations, financial engineering, and financial chicanery on Wall Street today. Post hoc ergo propter hoc, anyone? (Desmond 2019, 37).
And talk about straining credulity: Dont slavery and slaveholders have enough to answer for without tracing the genealogy of Dick Fuld, Hank Greenberg, and Angelo Mozilo directly back to antebellum Alabama? How about spending a little time looking at the more obvious case of Northern financiers during the Gilded Age, maybe by reviewing the complicated financial scams and schemes, mainly the work of non-Southerners, treated at length in works by Richard White, such as Railroaded and The Republic for Which It Stands (White 2011; White 2017)? Its okay to do so, by the way, for White has been published in NHACer collections. And what about Wall Street during the 1920s? None of this will do, however, for, in the words of Beckert and Rockman (words Desmond quotes approvingly), American slavery is necessarily imprinted on the DNA of American capitalism, establishing the genetic markers that purportedly explain the subprime crisis (Beckert and Rockman 2016, 3; Desmond 2019, 33). Who knew?
Closely related to the argument regarding the purported importance of slavery in creating U.S. mortgage markets is Desmonds contention, based in large part on Schermerhorns work, that slavery was central to the development of debt instruments of various kinds (including bills of exchange), international credit chains, and banking in the United States. The problem with this line of reasoning is that slavery or, more precisely, financing and investing in slaves and the slave trade were subsets of much broader sets: financing and investing in production, infrastructure (particularly transportation infrastructure), and trade in British North America and later the United States. Merchants and the investment communitysupported by evolving law, legal protocols, and practicesdeveloped a wide variety of tools, instruments, and institutions over time that rendered short-term lending and long-term investment more efficient, and often, but not always, safer. These tools, instruments, and institutions ranged from promissory notes to bills of exchange, from bills of credit to paper currency and stocks and bonds, and from private commercial banks to state banks to U.S. banks (Lamoreaux 1991; Bodenhorn 2000; Wright 2001; Wright 2002; Sylla 2002; Kilbourne 2006).
To be sure, the South was involved in international trade, especially in cotton, and thus was deeply enmeshed in this financial and credit system as it evolved. But few of the practices and institutions regarding debt targeted by Schermerhorn and thus Desmond were particular to the South, much less originated there, a notable exception being the introduction of short-lived plantation banks in the Lower South in the late 1820s and 1830s (Schermerhorn 2015, 95123; Murphy 2017). Generally speaking, much of the same debt and credit practices and institutions employed in cotton characterized the trade of flaxseed from colonial New York to England, of Pennsylvania wheat destined for Southern Europe, and of U.S. imports of delftware, Chinese goods, and chinoiserie. Similarly, long-term international investment in U.S. infrastructure, canals and railroads especially, in the antebellum period looked much the same whether in the North or the South. And crucially, bills of credit, paper money, the discounting of bills of exchange, commercial banks, life insurance, credit reporting, and so on, were all developed earlier and in more sophisticated ways in the North than in the South (Doerflinger 1986; Wright 2001; Wright 2002; Sylla 2002; Murphy 2010; Olegario 2006). Indeed, financial innovations such as theseand othershelp to explain how and why the economy of the North came to surpass that of the South in the antebellum period.
A third part of Desmonds financialization thesis centers on speculation, or, more to the point, a precocious Souths purported ability to corner the market on speculation, as it were. Desmond is basing his assertions here largely on work by NHACer Josh Rothman, both an article by Rothman in Slaverys Capitalism and, to a lesser extent, an earlier monograph by Rothman, Flush Times and Fever Dreams: A History of Capitalism and Slavery in the Age of Jackson (Rothman 2014). According to Desmond, Southern plantersarrogant, strutting, quarrelsome kinglets, W. E. B. Du Bois called them-thinking themselves invincible, and able to bend the laws of finance to their will, were shameless profiteers, prone to speculation, and oblivious to risk (Desmond 2019, 38). Such (group) character traits rendered the Southern economy inherently unstable, subject to booms and busts, no bust more calamitous than that beginning in the mid-1830s, generally known as the Panic of 1837. Desmond sees this panic as being strikingly similar to the 2008 financial crisis, and readily accepts Rothmans proclamation that during slavery Americans built a culture of speculation unique in its abandon (Rothman 2016, 126; Desmond 2019, 40). Really? Desmond then goes on to link this culture to, among other things, union-busting and gig jobs today, but rather than speculate about these rather tenuous claims, lets spend a little time on the concept of speculation and on the antebellum period itself.
Neither Rothman nor Desmond, it is clear, much like capitalism or at least the culture thereof. They go out of their way to try to meld together capitalism, speculation, gambling, and even criminality into one combustible mix. In order to make their position seem plausible, they focus on one economic phenomenonthe Panic of 1837and imply that it was standard or normative of slavery, the South, and capitalism. The problem is that it wasnt.
To be sure, capitalism, including Southern capitalism, historically has been subject to periodic bouts of instabilityshocks, recessions, panics, and, less frequently, depressionsbut over time has always bounced back and generally facilitated sustained economic growth wherever it has been planted and nurtured, including in the antebellum American South. The Southern economy, as suggested earlier, was one of the most dynamic economies in the world in the period between 1800 and 1860, enjoying a growth rate that few other societies at the time experienced. The standard of living of the free population on balance was also very high, and improving pretty much across the board, as Robert A. Margos work has demonstrated. According to Margo, between 1820 and 1860 the annual growth rate of real wages of common laborers was 0.97 percent in the South Atlantic census region and 0.85 percent in the South Central census region. The rates for artisans were somewhat lower and for white-collar workers somewhat higher, but annual growth of 0.90 percent, when compounded over forty years, results in an increase of 43 percent, extremely rapid for the time (Margo 2000, 51, table 3.3). This, despite the rough patch during part of the 1830sand a few other rough patches as well. To focus solely on and then extrapolate from one atypical subperiodthe Panic of 1837to the history of the South between 1800 and 1860 is shoddy methodologically, an instance at the very least of confirmation bias writ large.
One more point: Desmonds loose and inaccurate use of the concept of speculation. Desmond (and his scholarly alter ego, Rothman) both misuse the term and demonstrate little sense that they understand it in economic terms. Contrary to the insinuations in Desmonds essay, speculation and speculators are neither good nor bad, but efficient or inefficient, for both the practice and the practitioners play necessary roles in markets of all typesincluding financial markets and markets for art, wine, land, slaves, and so on.
Briefly, speculators buy or sell assets, hoping to gain from changes in their prices. Speculators often have short-term time horizons, but some prefer holding assets for medium- and long-term periods. In efficient financial markets, their role is to at once absorb excess risk and to provide liquidity when necessary, while other participantshedgers, arbitrageurs, and normal investorsperform other functions. In a sense, speculators, if effective, help to render more efficient the intertemporal distribution of resources under conditions of uncertainty, as no one knows what the future will hold. They can err, and when they do, both individual speculators and, in some cases, society as a whole can pay the price. But, like scholars and journalists, they perform certain necessary social functions. In America, and not just the South, some individuals have stepped up to perform such speculatory functions from the get-go (Coclanis 2015). And I for one am glad that many were successful in doing so.
The fourth part of Desmonds argument regarding slavery and financialization rests almost entirely on the work of Caitlin Rosenthal, one NHACer who is in fact comfortable with numbers and familiar with the tools, methods, and practices of economics (Rosenthal 2016; Rosenthal 2018). Rosenthal is particularly interested in the management practices of large cotton planters in the antebellum period, offering the provocative argument that the practices of such planters were marked, even characterized, by a striking concern for systematic measurement and surveillance. In her view, their business practices were extremely advanced for the time, rivaling those of the railroads, and certainly far more sophisticated than their agricultural peers in the North.
Rosenthals single most talked-about finding relates to planters bookkeeping practices. Basing her argument largely on cotton planters use of the blank plantation record and account books prepared, published, and distributed by Thomas Affleck of Mississippi during the antebellum period, Rosenthal contends that cotton planters were avid measurers, whose scientific managerial and bookkeeping practices incorporated the concept of depreciation and approached modern cost accounting. In so doing, they were quite innovative, anticipating much later developments normally associated in America with scientific management, F. W. Taylor, and so on. Rosenthals principal evidence, again, is the Affleck blank accounts, which commonly included fifteen blank forms for cotton planters (forms A through O), some of which, if filled out completely and properly, would allow for calculation of income and expenses, and the calculation of capital appreciation and depreciation regarding slaves, livestock, tools, and the like. To Rosenthal, the availability and use of Afflecks record and account books demonstrate, among other things, planters interest in agricultural improvement and business innovation, as well as their capitalist mentalité. Desmond, as is his wont, goes much further, employing Rosenthals findings to link slaverys capitalism to the financialization of the U.S. economy in recent decades and to various and sundry forms of worker exploitation, surveillance tools, and financial chicanery said to embody capitalism today (Rosenthal 2016; Rosenthal 2018).
Although in general I am a fan of Rosenthals and appreciate her overall body of work, her use of Affleck is questionable, and Desmonds is completely off the mark. Rosenthal herself in fact offers sotto voce some cautionary notes regarding both Affleck and his record and account books. Affleck was not a native Southerner but a Scot. He was in fact a bookkeeper for the Bank of Scotland before immigrating to the United States in 1832. During his first decade in the United States he worked as a clerk, a merchant, and an agricultural editor in New York City, Pennsylvania, Ohio, and Indiana, before showing up in Mississippi in 1842. Regarding his record and account books, Rosenthal points out that only a tiny minority of Southern cotton farmers possessed Afflecks books and, when used, the books were used unevenly and only partially completed (Rosenthal 2018, 9192, 94, 101). Olmstead and Rhode made the same points earlier in an excellent 2015 essay, wherein they punctured the notion that Southern plantations were factories in the fields. Furthermore, in her well-regarded book Every Farm a Factory: The Industrial Ideal in American Agriculture, Deborah Fitzgerald pointed out in 2003 that, as late as World War I, few farmers anywhere in the United States kept systematic accounts, much less practiced cost accounting (Fitzgerald 2003, 3357; Olmstead and Rhode 2015, 26972).
A recent study by a young scholar teaching at the University of Louisiana at Lafayette, Ian Beamish, qualifies the use of the Affleck books even more. In an impressive paper in the journal Agricultural History, Beamish subjected to close textual analysis all sixty-five of the filled-in Affleck account books known to exist for cotton plantations. The principal takeaway from Beamishs study is that the filled-in Affleck books were used almost exclusively as conventional agricultural record books, in a manner similar to records kept in the eighteenth-century South. Virtually no user (whether an owner or overseer) filled in forms M and Nthose needed for cost accountingand few were interested systematically in appreciation or depreciation. Rather, the books, which were often filled in incompletely, haphazardly, or incorrectly, were generally concerned with recording daily numbers and eventscotton picked by day and by slave, other labor performed, slave births and deaths, and so on. In his view, the books in and of themselves tell us little about the relationship between slavery and capitalism (Beamish 2021). Or, I might add, slavery in the antebellum South and financialization in the United States today.
Moreover, it is unfortunate that Desmond, in his haste to look forward, didnt spend at least a bit of time looking back, not merely or even necessarily on agriculture in the eighteenth-century South, but on the genealogy of capitalism itself. Instead of pressing to link slavery with present-day financialization, he would have been better served by telling us what he means by capitalism and why he places the antebellum South in the context of the evolution of this economic system in the West.
Desmonds reluctance to do so is not altogether surprising. As stated previously, scholars working under the NHAC umbrella are loathe to get into specifics about capitalism, old or new. For example, in their introduction to the important NHAC collection Slaverys Capitalism, Beckert and Rockman manage to resist the temptation to define precisely what they mean by capitalisma point mentioned by many criticsand Desmond follows suit. In this, the NHACers may be following the example set by Louis Armstrong, who, when asked about the definition of jazz, famously retorted, If you gotta ask, youll never know.
To be fair, NHACers, however reluctant to define capitalism, have suggested that the system or concept needs to be approached more broadly than it (whatever it is) has been until now. Thus they have tended to emphasize topics sometimes given relatively short shrift by earlier scholarswar, violence, race, the law, and so onin their analyses. Note that I say sometimes, because it is in fact possible (if one at all tries) to find plenty of earlier scholars of capitalism who have looked at each of these topics in detail. Be that as it may, we have recently seen the publication by an NHAC-related scholar, the aforementioned Caitlin Rosenthal, which includes a real definition of capitalism, or at least an explanation of how the author is using the term. In this piece, Rosenthal offers a succinct definition of capitalism, based, as she puts it, on (1) the commodification of labor, as it results from, (2) the accumulation of capital (Rosenthal 2020, 301). She doesnt historicize the development of said features, or go into the motive forces behind their development, but its a start.
It would be nice, however, if at some point NHAC scholars weighed in on these issues as well as others, such as the question of whether capitalism evolved slowly over centuries or emerged relatively rapidly; whether we should emphasize changes in production or in exchange or changes in other realms; where it emerged first and how it spread; the features necessary and sufficient in order to classify an economy as capitalist, and so on. It might take a while before we see this, however, because first the NHAC group would have to rediscover the fact that countless scholars thought about such matters rigorously before NHAC came onto the scene (Coclanis 2018; Clegg 2020).
An Alternative View of Capitalism and Slavery
To put my money where my mouth is, so to speak, I have long viewed the development of capitalism in evolutionary terms, as part of a long-term socioeconomic and cultural process relating to the proper, prescribed, sanctioned manner of organizing production and material life more generally, which process began in parts of Europe in the medieval period. The process expressed itself at different rates and unevenly in geographic terms over time, and was characterized, broadly speaking, by a growing sense among some individuals and groups of what today we conventionally call factors of productionland, labor, capital, and sometimes entrepreneurship (distinct from capital)and the progressive, if often distinctive, paths toward individuation, articulation, and commercialization of each.
This process cannot be assessed and evaluated solely on the basis of one considerationfor example, the presence or absence of free labor and wage relations as the dominant means of organizing and directing laborbut on an intricate axis involving other considerations as well, to wit, the degree of commercialization of other productive factors; a reasonable degree of competition; the alienability and transferability of property and credible state commitments regarding the protection of property rights; commodity production; the development and employment of increasingly sophisticated instruments and institutions relating to trade and exchange; rationality of spirit/market mentalité; and accumulation. This approach, which perforce entails a prominent role for verstehen, or interpretive understanding, is hardly parsimonious, but, at the end of the day, I am a historian, not an economist (Coclanis 1989, 4863).
When judged by the preceding criteria, parts of the American Southand various other parts of British Americacan be said to have been informed relatively early on by principles and institutions necessary and sufficient to be labeled capitalist economies and market-based societies. This was the case well before the antebellum period, the purported market revolution and all that. This label, despite or perhaps because of the prominence of slavery in some of these areasthe Chesapeake colonies, the Lower South, and the British West Indies. Slaverys capitalism then works for me, but a good bit earlier than is the case with NHAC.
If the forced link between antebellum slavery and financialization, not to mention with Martin Shkreli, is spurious, what can we say about slaverys role in the antebellum South, indeed in the antebellum United States more generally? Plenty, I would submit. First, regarding broad patterns: Only about a quarter of free families in the South held slaves. Of such families, the modal number of slaves held c. 1850 was one. Only about one of eight slaveholding familiesor a little over 3 percent of free families in totowould be considered planter families under what is arguably the most common definition, i.e., holding twenty or more slaves (Wright 1978, 2437; Oakes 1982, 3768, 24550; Bourne 2008; Olmstead and Rhode 2018). If we use another common definition for denoting planter statusholding twenty or more working handsthe proportion of planter families in the antebellum South shrinks accordingly.
Second, I would stress, with William H. Freehling, Lacy K. Ford, and others, that there was no one South, but many Souths, in some of which slavery was economically unimportant, in others by 1860 dying out (Freehling 1990, 936; Ford 2009). I would also point out that one of the most eminent experts on slavery and the slave trade, the late Philip D. Curtin, felt slavery was not important enough in North America to include the South in either edition of his classic The Rise and Fall of the Plantation Complex. In Curtins view, the U.S. South as a region was rather more a society with slaves than a true slave society, much less a plantation society (Curtin 1998, 10810).
After offering the preceding points, I would be quick to add that I dont buy Curtins argument regarding the South, and believe that the region, despite the small percentage of planters, should be considered a slave society controlled largely by planters (and their commercial and legal allies). Power, in other words, cannot be reduced to numbers and percentages alone.
Moreover, I would argue, as we saw just a bit earlier, that the Southern economy was organized for the most part along capitalist lines, and that the presence of slavery should not be viewed as evidence that the South was precapitalist. Rather, the institution, like the second serfdom in Eastern Europe, should be seen as an expression of an emerging capitalism, related to the mentalité of powerful interests and to the discrete labor conditions and needs in certain areas. The same liberal dimensions of early capitalism that led to freer and freer labor forms in some areas led elsewhere in some cases.
In parts of British America in the early modern period, especially the West Indies, the Chesapeake, and the Lower South (South Carolina and Georgia primarily), the market-driven desire of those Europeans and European Americans that sought to organize production of staple crops for exportsugar, tobacco, rice, and indigo primarilyled them in many, if not most, cases to favor enslaved African or African American laborers, and to establish and defend the self-serving institutional structure needed to sustain this labor system. Why? For several reasons. It was difficult in the Western Hemisphere, which was abundant in land and scarce in labor, to secure labor and retain it in place, particularly for onerous jobs in unhealthy climates. After various trials and experiments with other groups, European and European American agricultural entrepreneurs (settler capitalists?) and their commercial allies found that African and African American laborers constituted the best fit for their labor needs. Africans were in many cases already familiar with routinized agricultural work and in some cases may have possessed useful proprietary knowledge about certain crops (especially rice); they had some natural and inherited immunities to certain mosquito-borne diseases (malaria and yellow fever, most notably) that struck down greater proportions of other groups working in these areas; they were others, ethnically, racially, religiously, culturally, and so on, and as such were assumed to possess fewer natural rights, privileges, and immunities.
Slavery, however immoral from our point of view, was thus seen by powerful groups as the labor form that made the most economic sense in some areas, provided the supply of African slaves was sufficient to meet labor needs and their prices were sufficiently reasonable. For the most part, these requirements were met. Note though that the price of slaves, generally speaking, was not low but relatively high. Acquiring and deploying slaves was not based mainly on low-cost premises, then, but based, as Gavin Wright among others has shown, on the bundle of property rights associated with slavery, which allowed those who owned slaves to position them wherever they wanted to (even in unhealthy places); work them hard and long, even mercilessly; and retain them (and their progeny) as long as desired, even for life. These rights did not obtain to anywhere near the same degree with other labor forms, even with indentured or bonded labor, the closest analogues. These power dynamics explain the emergence of slavery in various capitalist societies in British America, and its prevalence in some (Wright 2006, 48122; Olmstead and Rhode 2018, 5). The fact that the slave template or pattern for labor relations endured even after some of the early reasons for its preference were no longer so relevantmost areas of the South were healthier than the low country of South Carolina or Georgia or the sugar parishes of southeastern Louisiana, whites could and did grow cotton without slaves, and so onsuggests a case for path dependence, or less insistently, path inflection or influence.
I would go on to argue that many deemed slavery vital to the Souths growth, from the period between the late seventeenth centurynot, mind you, from 1619 or even 1650 or 1660until the time of the Civil War. Slaves were deployed throughout the economy but were especially important as agricultural laborers producing subsistence crops as well as staples for export. The most important of such staples in the antebellum period was cotton. Again, though, remember that corn rather than cotton was the most valuable Southern crop, and that cotton, the leading export in the United States by far, nonetheless still composed a small share of GDP, usually around 5 or 6 percent (Olmstead and Rhode 2018; Wright 2020, 37378).
The NHAC view, which assumes cotton totally dominated the U.S. economy in the antebellum period, composing as much as 40 percent or even more of U.S. GDP, is grossly exaggerated, based largely on NHAC compatriot Edward Baptists unfamiliarity with standard national-income-accounting methods, particularly regarding the manner in which estimates of GDP are constructed. Such unfamiliarity led Baptist to double and sometimes triple count in estimating the size of the cotton economy by adding to the value of cotton production the value of all inputs used in its production, when, according to national-income-accounting protocols, these inputs are already subsumed into the sale price of cotton. This grievous measurement error would earn an undergraduate economics student a failing grade. This error, however, has not been admitted by Baptist and has gone unremarked upon by NHACers, who continue to use Baptists figures, despite their repudiation by measurement experts (Olmstead and Rhode 2018).
Continuing on, I would point out that in relative terms the Southern economy performed well in many ways in the antebellum period, and that the South, if severed from the rest of the United States and considered a stand-alone economy, would have been one of the wealthiest parts of the world in 1860 (Fogel and Engerman 1974, 1: 24757). The regions wealth was based largely on its agricultural economy, particularly upon that part of the sector deploying slave labor to produce staples for export, either internationally or extra-regionally. The regions manufacturing sector was not inconsequential, particularly for the age, but the South was clearly not urbanizing or industrializing nearly as rapidly as the North, preferring to pursue policies predicated on the continued push westward of its staple export economy, in so doing, expanding, as Drew McCoy put it long ago, across space rather than through time (McCoy 1980). The planters, merchants, bankers, and politicians who led the push westward were more or less forward-looking and modern in their thinking, but they hardly represented the capitalist vanguard in the Western world at the time.
If mean income and wealth of the free population in the South rose significantly in the course of the period, the region was home to many poor people and was marked by considerable inequality, even excluding the 3540 percent of the population that was enslaved. With this point in mind, logic would seem to dictate that we ask, who benefited from slavery? (Coclanis 2010b, 495502). Not the slaves themselves, obviously, and much of the free population in the region probably didnt gain much either, although certainly some did via economic links and connections to the slave-labor-based agricultural economy. How about the region qua region?
This is a difficult question to answer because the trajectory of the Southern economy was first disrupted and then irrevocably changed with the Civil War, but I have argued at length elsewhere, along with many other scholars, that, although the Southern economy was growing in the antebellum period, the growth path taken was not necessarily conducive to long-term economic development. Like other plantation economies around the world, that of the South was unbalanced and overly specialized, marked by relatively low levels of urbanization (especially in the interior), a rudimentary conveyor-belt transportation system designed to facilitate exporting and importing rather than knitting together the region as a whole, and low levels of investment in human capital. Few plantation economies anywhere in the world have ever developed into modern high-performance economiesnone based primarily upon slave labor haveand numerous studies have demonstrated the long-term negative effects of plantation-based slavery on those parts of the South where it took firm hold. So slavery or slaverys capitalism almost certainly did not promote the economic well-being of the region over the long run (Genovese 1965, 1339; Wright 1978, 10727; Coclanis 1989, 11158; Sokoloff and Engerman 2000; Mitchener and McLean 2003; Nunn, 2008; Majewski 2016; Wright 2017; Coclanis 2020).
Consumers of agricultural products produced by Southern slaves likely paid a bit lesswhether in the South, the North, or Europethan they would have had said products been produced by free labor. But because cotton composed only about 5 percent of U.S. output, this gain would have been fairly small, especially because free labor was able to produce it at a low cost, as shown after emancipation. Similarly, residents of nonslave states probably paid a little less in taxes than they would have because a good part of the U.S. governments revenue came from duties on imported goods, financed directly or indirectly by exports of slave-produced cotton, rice, and so on. Again, though, the gain would be small because taxes were only about 2 percent of GDP. To be sure, it is true that some merchants, bankers, and manufacturers within and without the South benefited in various ways from their involvement in the slave system as well. Assessing the degree to which discrete individuals and individual firms benefited is difficult, however, because little as yet is known regarding the opportunity costs they would have incurred by forgoing involvement in the slave economy (DeLong 2007; Coclanis 2010b, 495502).
One thing seems clear though. The U.S. economyunlike the Southern economywas not based on slavery in the nineteenth century. Although cotton produced in the South was important early on to the textile industry in the Northeast, in the larger scheme of things, the most important economic developments of the centuryurbanization and industrialization in the northeastern quadrant of the United States (the area north of the Ohio River and east of the Mississippi) and the creation of the dynamic agro-industrial complex in the Middle Westowed relatively little (if anything) to slavery (Page and Walker 1991). Cotton, one recalls, became much more important in the South after the Civil War, emancipation, and the demise of slavery than it ever was before the warcotton production in the region did not peak until the late 1920sand cottons importance to the American textiles industry followed the same pattern.
Indeed, it is more accurate to say that slavery distorted rather than directed capitalist development in America. Slavery constituted an illiberal expression of early capitalism in certain contexts in labor-scarce, land-abundant areas during the so-called primitive accumulation. The principal thrust, the major theme, as it were, of capitalism was liberal and progressive, resulting in greater economic freedom. The forces unleashed by capitalism that brought slavery to British America and sustained slavery for a period thereafter later led to the rise among some, then among many, of what Thomas Haskell has famously called a humanitarian sensibility that led Great Britain and the United States to abolish slavery relatively early in the modern period, far earlier than in many other parts of the world, particularly in Africa and the Middle East.
Slavery in the American South was an abomination, but Matthew Desmond, taking his cues from the NHAC, grossly misrepresents it in order to render financialization its lineal descendent. Clearly, Desmond would do well to look elsewhere for the answer to who or what begat Martin Shkreli.
References
Bales, Kevin. 2012. Disposable People: New Slavery in the Global Economy. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press.
Baptist, Edward E. 2014. The Half Has Never Been Told: Slavery and the Making of American Capitalism. New York: Basic Books.
Beamish, Ian W. 2021. A Complicated Humbug: Slavery, Capitalism, and Accounts in the Cotton South. Agricultural History 95, no. 1: 3668.
Beckert, Sven. 2014. Empire of Cotton: A Global History. New York: Viking.
_____, and Seth Rockman. 2016. Introduction: Slaverys Capitalism. In Slaverys Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development, edited by Sven Beckert and Seth Rockman, 127. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Bodenhorn, Howard. 2000. A History of Banking in Antebellum America: Financial Markets and Economic Development in an Era of Nation-Building. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Bourne, Jenny. 2008. Slavery in the United States. EH.NET Encyclopedia, edited by Robert Whaples, March 26.
Clegg, John. 2015. Capitalism and Slavery. Critical Historical Studies 2, no. 2: 281304.
_____. 2020. A Theory of Capitalist Slavery. Journal of Historical Sociology 33, no. 1: 7498.
Coates, Ta-Nehisi. 2014. The Case for Reparations. The Atlantic 313, no. 5: 5471.
Coclanis, Peter A. 1989. The Shadow of a Dream: Economic Life and Death in the South Carolina Low Country, 16701920. New York: Oxford University Press.
_____. 2000. Tracking the Economic Divergence of the North and the South. Southern Cultures 6, no. 4: 82103.
_____. 2010a. The Audacity of Hope: Economic History Today. AHA Perspectives on History 48, no. 1: 2125.
_____. 2010b. The Economics of Slavery. In The Oxford Handbook of Slavery in the Americas, edited by Robert Paquette and Mark M. Smith, 498512. Oxford and New York: Oxford University Press.
_____. 2015. Disorder and Early Sorrow. Journal of American Studies 49, no. 2. At https://doi.org/10.1017/S002187581500016X.
_____. 2018. Slavery, Capitalism, and the Problem of Misprision. Journal of American Studies 52, no. 3: E46.
_____. 2019. The 1619 Project Is the 2019 Projectand the 2020 Project. The Spectator (U.S.A.), December 24.
_____. 2020. More Pricks Than Kicks: The Southern Economy in the Long Twentieth Century. Study the South, May 26.
_____, and David L. Carlton. 2001. The Crisis in Economic History. Challenge: The Magazine of Economic Affairs 44, no. 6: 93103.
Curtin, Philip D. 1998. The Rise and Fall of the Plantation Complex: Essays in Atlantic History, 2nd ed. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Degler, Carl. 1959. Out of Our Past: The Forces That Shaped Modern America. New York: Harper & Row.
DeLong, Brad. 2007. Who Benefited from North American Slavery before the Civil War?
Desmond, Matthew. 2007. On the Fireline: Living and Dying with Wildland Firefighters. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
_____. 2016. Evicted: Poverty and Profit in the American City. New York: Crown.
_____. 2019. In Order to Understand the Brutality of American Capitalism, You Have to Start on the Plantation. New York Times Magazine, August 18, pp. 3040.
_____, and Mustafa Emirbayer. 2015. The Racial Order. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
_____. 2016. 2nd ed., 2020. Race in America. New York: Norton.
Doerflinger, Thomas M. 1986. A Vigorous Spirit of Enterprise: Merchants and Economic Development in Revolutionary Philadelphia. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
Engerman, Stanley L. 2000. Slavery at Different Times and Places. American Historical Review 105 (April): 48084.
Feinberg, Ashley. 2019. The New York Times Unites vs. Twitter. Slate, August 15.
Fitzgerald, Deborah. 2003. Every Farm a Factory: The Industrial Ideal in American Agriculture. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Fogel, Robert William, and Stanley L. Engerman. 1974. Time on the Cross: The Economics of American Negro Slavery. 2 vols. Boston: Little, Brown.
Ford, Lacy K. 2009. Deliver Us from Evil: The Slavery Question in the Old South. New York: Oxford University Press.
Freehling, William H. 1990. The Road to Disunion, vol. 1. New York: Oxford University Press.
Genovese, Eugene D. 1965. The Political Economy of Slavery: Studies in the Economy and Society of the Slave South. New York: Pantheon.
Hannah-Jones, Nikole. 2019. The Idea of America. New York Times Magazine, August 18, pp. 1426.
Hansen, Bradley A. 2014. The Back of Ed Baptists Envelope. Bradley A. Hansens Blog, October 30.
Harris, Leslie M. 2020. I Helped Fact-Check the 1619 Project. The Times Ignored Me. Politico, March 6.
Haskell, Thomas L. Capitalism and the Rise of the Humanitarian Sensibility. American Historical Review 90, no. 2: 33961 and no. 3: 54766.
Hilt, Eric. 2017. Economic History, Historical Analysis, and the New History of Capitalism. Journal of Economic History 77, no. 2: 51136.
Johnson, Michael P., and James L. Roark. 1984. Black Masters: A Free Family of Color in the Old South. New York: Norton.
Johnson, Walter. 2013. River of Dark Dreams: Slavery and Empire in the Cotton Kingdom. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Kilbourne, Richard Holcombe, Jr. 2006. Slave Agriculture and Financial Markets: The Bank of the United States in Mississippi, 18311852. London: Pickering & Chatto.
Lamoreaux, Naomi R. 1991. Information Problems and Banks Specialization in Short-Term Commercial Lending: New England in the Nineteenth Century. In Inside the Business Enterprise: Historical Perspectives on the Use of Information, edited by Peter Temin, 161204. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Magness, Phillip W. 2020a. What the 1619 Projects Critics Get Wrong about Lincoln. In Magness, The 1619 Project: A Critique. Great Barrington, Mass.: American Institute for Economic Research.
_____. 2020b. A Comment on the New History of Capitalism. The Economic Historian, September 15.
Majewski, John. 2016. Why Did Northerners Oppose the Expansion of Slavery? Economic Development and Education in the Limestone South. In Slaverys Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development, edited by Sven Beckert and Seth Rockman, 27798. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Margo, Robert A. 2000. Wages and Labor Markets in the United States, 18201860. National Bureau of Economic Research Series on Long-Term Factors in Economic Development. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Martin, Bonnie. 2016. Neighbor-to-Neighbor Capitalism: Local Credit Networks and the Mortgaging of Slaves. In Slaverys Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development, edited by Sven Beckert and Seth Rockman, 10721.Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
McCoy, Drew R. 1980. The Elusive Republic: Political Economy in Jeffersonian Virginia. New York: Norton.
Mitchener, Kris James, and Ian W. McLean. 2003. The Productivity of U.S. States Since 1880. Journal of Economic Growth 8, no. 1: 73114.
Morgan, Philip D. 2019. Virginia Slavery in Atlantic Context, 15501650. In Virginia 1619: Slavery and Freedom in the Making of English America, edited by Paul Musselwhite, Peter C. Mancall, and James Horn, 85107. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.
Murphy, Sharon Ann. 2005. Securing Human Property: Slavery, Life Insurance, and Industrialization in the Upper South. Journal of the Early Republic 25, no. 4: 61552.
_____. 2010. Investing in Life: Insurance in Antebellum America. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
_____. 2017. Banking on Slavery in the Antebellum South. Unpublished paper, Yale University Economic History Workshop, May 1.
New York Times Magazine. 2019. The 1619 Project. August 18. Also see the Pulitzer Centers 1619 Project website.
Nunn, Nathan. 2008. Slavery, Inequality, and Economic Development in the Americas: An Examination of the Engerman-Sokoloff Hypothesis. In Institutions and Economic Performance, edited by Elhanan Helpman, 14880. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Oakes, James. 1982. The Ruling Race: A History of American Slaveholders. New York: Knopf.
_____. 2020. A Few Random Thoughts on Capitalism and Slavery. The Economic Historian,September 21.
Olegario, Rowena. 2006. A Culture of Credit: Embedding Trust and Transparency in American Business. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Olmstead, Alan L., and Paul W. Rhode. 2008. Biological Innovation and Productivity Growth in the Antebellum Cotton Economy. Journal of Economic History 68, no. 4: 112371.
_____. 2015. Were Antebellum Cotton Plantations Factories in the Fields? In Enterprising America: Businesses, Banks, and Credit Markets in Historical Perspective, edited by William J. Collins and Robert A. Margo, 24576. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
_____. 2018. Cotton, Slavery, and the New History of Capitalism. Explorations in Economic History 67, no. 1: 117.
Page, Brian, and Richard Walker. 1991. From Settlement to Fordism: The Agro-Industrial Revolution in the American Midwest. Economic Geography 67, no. 4: 281315.
Patterson, Orlando. 1982. Slavery and Social Death: A Comparative Study. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
Rockett, Darvell. 2019. Five Minutes with Nikole Hannah-Jones, the Architect behind the New York Times 1619 Project. Chicago Tribune, October 10.
Rosenthal, Caitlin. 2016. Slaverys Scientific Management. In Slaverys Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development, edited by Sven Beckert and Seth Rockman, 6286. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
_____. 2018. Accounting for Slavery: Masters and Management. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.
_____. 2020. Capitalism When Labor Was Capital: Slavery, Power, and Price in Antebellum America. Capitalism: A Journal of History and Economics 1, no. 2: 296337.
Rothman, Joshua D. 2014. Flush Times and Fever Dreams: A Story of Capitalism and Slavery in the Age of Jackson. Athens: University of Georgia Press.
_____. 2016. The Contours of Cotton Capitalism: Speculation, Slavery, and the Economic Panic in Mississippi, 18321841. In Slaverys Capitalism: A New History of American Economic Development, edited by Sven Beckert and Seth Rockman, 12245. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.
Schermerhorn, Calvin. 2015. The Business of Slavery and the Rise of Capitalism, 18151860. New Haven: Yale University Press.
Schuessler, Jennifer. 2013. In History Departments, Its Up with Capitalism. New York Times, April 6.
Schweninger, Loren. 1990. Black Property Owners in the South, 17901915. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.
Silverstein, Jake. 2020. An Update to the 1619 Project. New York Times, March 11.
Sokoloff, Kenneth L., and Stanley L. Engerman. 2000. Institutions, Factor Endowments, and Paths of Development in the New World. Journal of Economic Perspectives 14, no. 3: 21732.
Sowell, Thomas. 2019. Discrimination and Disparities, rev. ed. New York: Hachette.
Stephens, Bret. 2020. The 1619 Chronicles. New York Times, October 9. At https://www.nytimes.com/2020/10/09/opinion/nyt-1619-project-criticisms.html.
Sylla, Richard. 2002. Financial Systems and Economic Modernization. Journal of Economic History 62, no. 2: 27792.
White, Richard. 2011. Railroaded: The Transcontinentals and the Making of Modern America. New York: Norton.
_____. 2017. The Republic for Which It Stands: The United States During Reconstruction and the Gilded Age, 18651896. New York: Oxford University Press.
Williamson, Samuel H., and Louis P. Cain. 2020. Measuring Slavery in 2016 Dollars. Measuring Worth.
Wood, Peter R. 2020. 1620: A Critical Response to the 1619 Project. New York: Encounter Books.
Wright, Erik Olin, and Joel Rogers. 2015. American Society: How It Really Works, 2nd ed. New York: Norton.
Wright, Gavin. 1978. The Political Economy of the Cotton South: Households, Markets, and Wealth in the Nineteenth Century. New York: Norton.
____. 2006. Slavery and American Economic Development. Baton Rouge: Louisiana State University Press.
_____. 2020. Slavery and Anglo-American Capitalism Revisited. Economic History Review 73, no. 2: 35383.
Wright, Robert E. 2001. Origins of Commercial Banking in America, 17501800. Lanham, Md.: Rowman and Littlefield.
_____. 2002. The Wealth of Nations Rediscovered: Integration and Expansion in American Financial Markets, 17801850. New York: Cambridge University Press.
_____. 2017. The Poverty of Slavery: How Unfree Labor Pollutes the Economy. London: Palgrave Macmillan.