List Price: | ||
Price: | $14.95 | |
Discount: | $5.00 (Save 25%) |
Formats |
Paperback |
eBook |
List Price: | ||
Price: | $14.95 | |
Discount: | $5.00 (Save 25%) |
Formats |
Paperback |
eBook |
Overview
Changing the Guard is an authoritative survey of one of the most controversial aspects of criminal justice and corrections: the growing use of private prisons.
When prison privatization began in the United States in the early 1980s, many policy analysts claimed it would increase costs, decrease quality and erode state authority. Has it? Changing the Guard brings together leading criminal justice researchers to tackle this and related questions: Does prison privatization make economic sense? What are the prospects for enlarging prison privatization?
Changing the Guard also examines the broader questions that surround the prison privatization debate: What are the historical precedents for prison privatization? What do we know about punishment and recidivism? How long must a prison sentence be to deter crime? Are too many people in prison or too few? Should legal reform take precedence over prison reform to ensure that privatization does not simply make the criminal justice system more efficient at abusing civil liberties and executing legal injustices?
Contents
- Foreword
Charles Logan - Chapter 1: Introduction
Alexander Tabarrok - Chapter 2 The Economics of Prisons
Ken Avio - Chapter 3 Correctional Privatization: An Assessment of Its Historical Origins, Present Status, and Future Prospects
Charles Thomas - Chapter 4 Prisons and Corrections
Samuel Jan Brakel and Kimberly Ingersoll Gaylord - Chapter 5 Do We Want the Production of Prisons Services to Be More Efficient?
Bruce Benson
Detailed Summary
- Until the mid-1980s, the number of privatized jails and prisons could be counted on the fingers of one hand. Overcrowding and rising costs, however, prompted lawmakers to take prison privatization seriously. By 2002 there were 184 fully privatized jails and prisons in operation or under construction around the world, with total housing capacity of approximately 143,000, including 153 in the United States, with a capacity of nearly 120,000. (p. 77)
- Private prisons have grown faster than the prison population. From 1991 to 2000, the U.S. prison population, including those confined in local jails, increased by 65 percent. During the same time period, the worldwide capacity of privatized facilities increased an astounding 849 percent. (p.78)
- Private prisons are cheaper and faster to build. Construction-cost savings are typically 15 to 25 percent. (p.134) In Florida, a prison with capacity for 1,318 inmates was built privately for $69.9 million, while another of comparable size was built publicly for $85.7 million, 23 percent higher. In Texas, a private company built a detention facility for the U.S. Immigration and Nationalization Service (INS) in six months, as compared to the INSs own average of 2.5 years. (p.135) Cost savings typically are larger the more authority the private firm has to choose where and how to build prison facilities. (p. 136)
- Private prisons are cheaper to operate. Twelve of 14 studies found that private prisons are 5 to 28 percent cheaper to run. (p. 137) If all the studies on cost savings published in the U.S., Australia, and Great Britain were taken as a group, estimated operating-cost savings would be 10 to 15 percent. (p.139)
- Critics predictions of legal obstacles to prison privatization havent panned out. No correctional facility management contract awarded by a local, state, or federal agency has been invalidated on legal or constitutional grounds. Nor has any agency faced legal action as a result of alleged wrongful acts or omissions of a private prison firm. (p.78)
- Opposition to private prisons has limited their adoption. The public sector rarely competes directly with private firms and very few public prisons have been converted to private. (p.81)
Changing the Guard: Private Prisons and the Control of Crime, edited by Alexander Tabarrok (Research Director, The Independent Institute), examines a controversial aspect of prisons and crime controlthe growing use of private prisons. Virtually unheard of twenty years ago, private prisons are now a big business not only in the United States but increasingly in Canada, England, Australia, South Africa, and elsewhere. Although private prisons now house approximately 120,000 prisoners in the United States, the private sector is still small relative to the total prison population of some 2,000,000 prisoners.
In the United States, private prisons have grown because of prison overcrowding and the desire of the states and Federal government to cut costs. Numerous studies now exist demonstrating that private prisons have operating costs approximately 15 percent lower than equivalent public prisons. In addition, private prisons can be located and built more quickly than public prisons.
Although there was initially a concern that cost-savings might come at the expense of quality, the data has not borne this out. Whether in terms of physical quality of the prison, legal access, food quality, and other measures, private prisons have been found to be as good as public prisons and sometimes better. Thus after surveying some 333 indicators of quality at two public and one similar private prison, noted prison-privatization expert Charles H. Logan (University of Connecticut) concluded that the private prison outperformed its governmental counterparts on nearly every dimension. Surveys of inmates also find a preference for private prisons because they tend to control violence, committed by staff and prisoners, better than at public prisons (p. 141).
The Economics of Prisons
Private prisons cannot be evaluated without also evaluating prisons and punishment more generally. Economist Kenneth Avio (University of Victoria) opens Changing the Guard with an analysis of the broader questions surrounding the private-prison debate: Does prison pay? What do we know about punishment and recidivism? How large is the crime-deterrence effect? What is an optimal prison sentence? Are too many people in prison or too few? Avio concludes that, on average, the criminal justice system works, but the system could be improved dramatically if attention were focused on the small number of criminals who commit the vast majority of crimes. Drug offenders and other non-violent criminals are jailed far too much.
Avio focuses his survey on the economic analysis of crime but concludes that we need a more comprehensive understanding of human nature than that depicted in the economic model. We know little about how and why a shared moral order is developed and maintained. This change in perspective . . . suggests a return to a relatively neglected part of the research program Adam Smith laid out in 1791. Analysis of the social institutions that inculcate self-command and that otherwise function as civilizing forces in our society, should be part and parcel of the research strategy social scientists adopt to help understand and control crime.
Correctional Privatization: Past, Present, and Future
Private prison authority Charles Thomas (Homeland Security Corporation) provides the empirical context for understanding the debate over private prisons, examining their historical origins, present status and future prospects. Intriguingly, Thomas notes that many aspects of the criminal justice system have long been privatized. Many states, for example, house one-third to two-thirds of their interned juveniles in private facilities. Seen in this light, opposition to private prisons is difficult to understand.
Thomas argues that the full benefits of privatization are threatened by governmentalization, i.e., the tendency of contracting agencies to require contractors to run things exactly as a government bureaucracy would, only cheaper. In some cases, private prisons have even been required to have the same menus as their government counterparts! The real benefits of privatization come when private firms are allowed to innovate to find new and better ways of doing things. Flexibility in contract design, however, raises the possibility that private firms will take advantage of the government. Addressing these issues may require careful design of contracts and more attention paid to monitoring outputs rather than inputs. Further diffusion of best practices, such as performance incentives and on-site compliance monitors that have developed in twenty years of contracting, can manage these twin difficulties.
Privatization and Public Policy
Samuel Jan Brakel (Issac Ray Center) and Kimberly Gaylord (DePaul University College of Law) survey the evidence on construction cost, operating expenditure, quality and other factors and find strong reasons to favor prison privatization in the United States. Brakel and Gaylord also examine the moral and ethical arguments against private prisons and find them deficient. Perhaps the most compelling evidence that prison privatization works is that prisoners themselves have few objections to private prisons.
However, Bruce Benson (Florida State University and The Independent Institute) raises some objections to prison privatization, even while accepting the findings of lower costs and higher quality. When secondary effects are considered, Benson suggests, prison privatization may be seen as a Faustian bargain resulting in a more efficient way to punish people for victimless crimes or for breaking laws that may be unjust. The Roman Empires private tax collectors, for example, may have raised revenue efficiently, but its hard to see that such efficiency benefited the populace. Thus, legal reform should considered along side prison privatization.
Benson himself notes that public law enforcement bureaucracies have been among the most powerful lobbyists for expanding the war on drugs, which increases the demand for their services. The California Correctional Peace Officers Association, for example, was a key funder of Californias three-strikes ballot initiative and is today a key opponent of limiting three strikes only to violent offenders. The union also works to restrict drug policies that promote treatment over imprisonment, Benson notes.
Owners of private prisons would also have an incentive to lobby for more prisons, but there is a difference. The union has a virtual monopoly on prison workers, so any increase in prisons benefits its constituents. But even today there are multiple firms that run private prisons; thus, a firm that lobbies to expand prisons in general (as opposed to lobbying to expand its prisons) does more to benefit its competitors than it does to benefit itself. Indeed, as the private-prison industry grows larger, the incentive for any one firm to lobby for general prison-expanding policies declines.
Conclusion
Although prison privatization has slowed somewhat during the twenty-first century, its rapid progress during the 1990sand the serious fiscal troubles experienced recently by the federal government and many state governmentssuggests that the issues examined in Changing the Guard make its release timely. Not only has the time for prison privatization come, its relative infancy suggests that the number of private prisons will increase, thus making the practice less controversial over time. As editor Alexander Tabarrok puts it in the books Introduction: At present, private firms compete primarily with public bureauswhich is sort of like the repeated competition between the Harlem Globetrotters and the Washington Generals. But to raise the level of the industry truly, it is necessary that the best compete against the best. Competition works better when all the competitors have strong incentives to achieve, which means that privatization will be more successful when a large share of the prison industry is privatized, and competition between private firm and private firm is the norm.
Praise
Changing the Guard is the authoritative and definitive book on prison privatization. It brilliantly examines the full range of issueshistory, status, economics, efficiency effectiveness, equity, morality, and recidivism, and addresses the fundamental societal costs and benefits of incarceration itself.
E. S. Savas, Professor, School of Public Affairs, Baruch College, City University of New York
If you want to understand private prisons and how they fit into the criminal justice system, you need the information and analysis in this book. Changing the Guard does an outstanding job of combining a firm grounding of what we know about private prisons and how they work with great analysis of the economics and policy issues that surround the use of private prisons. Then it frosts the cake with some unique perspectives on both criminal justice and private prisons. Anyone who needs to make decisions about private prisons needs to read this book.
Adrian T. Moore, Executive Director, Reason Public Policy Institute
Changing the Guard is first-rate analysis of a moribund industry, its political-bureaucratic ills and the modest success of so-called prison privatization over the last two decades. Real experts point toward a crucial reform: foster competition for renewable contracts among public and private prison agencies to operate every facility, not just a few new ones.
Morgan O. Reynolds, former Chief Economist, U.S. Department of Labor
This book brings refreshing relief from the widespread cant and negativity about prisons in general and privately operated prisons in particular. . . . So much written about private prisons is tendentious and ideological, in contrast to the carefully researched contributions here.
Charles H. Logan, Professor of Sociology, University of Connecticut (from the Foreword)
Author
Alexander Tabarrok is Research Director for The Independent Institute, Assistant Editor of The Independent Review, and Associate Professor of Economics, George Mason University. He received his Ph.D. in economics from George Mason University, and he has taught at the University of Virginia and Ball State University. Dr. Tabarrok is also the editor of the Independent Institute books, Entrepreneurial Economics: Bright Ideas from the Dismal Science (Oxford University Press) and The Voluntary City: Choice, Community and Civil Society (University of Michigan Press). His scholarly articles have appeared in the Journal of Law and Economics, Public Choice, Economic Inquiry, Journal of Health Economics, Journal of Theoretical Politics, Review of Austrian Economics, Kyklos and many other journals. Dr. Tabarrok is the recipient of the Snavely Award, and he has been an Earhart Foundation Fellow and George A. and Frances Ball Foundation Fellow.
About the Foreword Author
Charles H. Logan is Professor of Sociology at the University of Connecticut and an internationally known authority on criminology and private prisons.