On Monday, August 5, 2024, Judge Amit Mehta of Washington, DCs federal district court ruled that Google exercises an unlawful monopoly of the market for general search engines (GSEs). GSEs are software applications that allow users of web browsers (like Googles Chrome, Microsofts Edge, Apples Safari, and Mozillas Firefox) to hunt for information on the web by entering keywords on their digital devices.
Judge Mehtas finding of an unlawful Google monopoly accepted evidence presented by the US Department of Justice during a 10-week-long trial last year. The DOJ argued that Googles GSE nowadays accounts for 90 percent of the Internet searches initiated by consumers, a share that has grown from 80 percent a decade ago.
What is more, Judge Mehta concluded that Google violated the Sherman Act (1890) by paying billions of dollars to web browsing companies in return for making Googles GSE the default option for searching the Internet. Doing so supposedly undermined competition in the GSE market by foreclosing other search engines. But that reasoning is based on a misunderstanding of market processes wherein even a small competitive fringe of rivals stands ready to expand their market shares if a dominant firm stumbles and fails continuously to meet consumers expectations. Market shares routinely are manipulated by antitrust law enforcers; paraphrasing Judge Learned Hand, a companys mere size does not by itself offend the antitrust laws.
According to the supporters of Judge Mehtas landmark decision, the ruling on Googles search dominance was the first antitrust decision of the modern Internet era in a case against a technology giant. Vanderbilt law school professor Rebecca Haw Allensworth gushed that this is the most important antitrust case of the century, and its the first of a big slate of cases to come down against Big Tech.
Not so fast. Every web browser, including Googles Chrome, allows users of desktop computers and other smart devices to change their browsers default GSE easily by clicking on preferences or settings and choosing another search engine at no additional charge. Chrome and its rivals make money not from GSE users but by selling advertisers access to those users.
Even Judge Mehta recognized that Googles GSE now dominates the Internet search market because of its superior product quality and numerous innovations (read: the scale and scope necessary to deliver high-quality search experiences). If that were not true, consumers would, with little effort, switch to another search engine (e.g., Yahoo!, Microsofts Bing, DuckDuckGo, Yandex).
It likewise is not true that US v. Google is the first antitrust case of the modern Internet era in a case against a technology giant unless the definition of modern is restricted to the twenty-first century. The honor (or dishonor) of being first goes to US v. Microsoft, a case decided in 1998, in which the Justice Department alleged that the defendant was guilty of exercising an unlawful monopoly because, at the time, Microsoft accounted for 90 percent of the market for Intel-compatible PC operating systems shipped in the United States. That dominance supposedly was fortified by the companys incorporation of its Internet Explorer web browser into Windows 95 (or 98) at no additional charge, to the detriment of Netscapes Navigator and other web browsing rivals. (Because GSEs were in their infancy then, search engines, called indexers or web crawlers, played no role in the litigation.)
Courts have frequently accepted a 90 percent market share as the benchmark for declaring successful business enterprises to be unlawful monopolies throughout antitrust law enforcement history. That was the bright line in the mother of all monopolization cases against Standard Oil in 1911 and the prosecution of the Aluminum Company of America (Alcoa) in 1945. More recently, in the yet-to-be-decided US v. Apple, the Department of Justice alleged monopoly based on the iPhones 65 to 70 percent share of smartphone sales.
Before market shares can be computed, the product and geographic boundaries of a relevant antitrust market must be drawn. Therein lies the rub. The narrower a markets boundaries, the smaller the number of sellers (and buyers) actively participating in it, and the larger each of those sellers market shares will be. (If the relevant market for dry cleaning services is the corner of one street intersection, the sole dry cleaner located there is a monopolist.)
The nadir of market definition exercises was reached in 1966 when the Justice Department blocked a merger between Vons Grocery Co. and Shopping Bag Food Stores because the combination would have created a retailer accounting for just seven percent of Los Angeles grocery store sales.
Antitrust law enforcers are predisposed to draw market boundaries tightly, often ignoring sellers that compete actually or potentially to constrain the sellers within those boundaries. In Alcoa, for instance, the Department of Justice and the courts excluded previously produced aluminum that, even in the 1940s, routinely was recycled into new products that competed with the virgin aluminum ingots the defendant was said to have monopolized. If recyclable aluminum had been included in the relevant market, Alcoas market share would have been 30 percent, not 90 percent.
Staples has been trying to acquire Office Depot since 1997. The initial merger proposal was blocked by the Federal Trade Commission on the theory that the combination would undermine competition between office-supply superstores, a market definition that encompassed just those two companies plus Office Max. Office supplies sold by Walmart, mail-order outlets like Quill, and smaller Mom-and-Pop retailers of office supplies were excluded from the FTCs market. In announcing opposition to the recently proposed $24.6 billion merger between Kroger and Albertsons, the FTC likewise has claimed that competition would be impaired in the market for traditional grocery stores, a market definition that ignores groceries sold by Walmart, Amazon, Costco, Trader Joes, and numerous other local and online retailers.
Relevant antitrust markets are only snapshots of the contours of dynamically changing competitive market processes. By the time a federal court order broke up Standard Oil Companys monopoly, new oil fields were opening in West Texas, and new refineries were coming online. The entries of Texaco and other competitors ate into Standards share of the markets for crude oil and kerosene (the principal refinery product of the day), dropping it quickly from 90 to 70 percent.
Google was not founded until September 4, 1998, supplying yet more evidence of the dynamism of Big Tech.
It bears emphasizing that controlling 90 percent of a relevant antitrust market is not a monopoly, defined in economics textbooks as the extremely rare case of a single seller of a product for which, in consumers eyes, no good substitutes are available. Google is not a monopoly of general search engines. It surely is large, even dominant, in the GSE market if that definition is apt, but size by itself does not mean that consumers are or have been harmed.
So, why does Google pay billions to Apple and other web-browsing companies to make Googles GSE the default search engine option, an option that consumers can easily change? For the same reason that food manufacturers pay slotting fees to grocery stores for prime shelf space product placements, and movie and television production companies are paid for showing branded merchandise briefly to their audiences. Those payments supply competitive edges in reaching prospective buyers but do not make consumers worse off.
The developers of rival GSEs can choose to make their search engines as good as or better than Googles, investments that seem within the capabilities of Microsoft and perhaps Yahoo! Alternatively, they could offer to pay web-browsing companies more than Google does to overcome their evident inferiorities as default search engines. Or rival GSEs could mimic DuckDuckGos strategy of attracting users by emphasizing privacy features (Our ads dont follow you around) or other attributes that consumers value.
Default options are sticky because of consumers inertia, but they are not locked in stone. Superior functionality always finds a way into markets, including high-tech ones. Vigorous competition (even between small numbers of rivals) serves consumers better than antitrust intervention ever has.